"The New Industrial State"
A review by Carroll Quigley in The Washington Sunday Star,
June 25 1967,
of the book :
THE NEW INDUSTRIAL STATE
By John Kenneth Galbraith
"The New Industrial State"
THE NEW INDUSTRIAL STATE
By John Kenneth Galbraith
Houghton Mifflin.
427 pages, index. $6.95.
This is an immensely important book. It
should be read, analysed, and un-emotionally discussed, not by
economists, but by citizens. The economists, like most academicians, are
hampered by their specialist training from seeing their subject in its
full social context, and will be particularly offended by this volume,
whose lessons, if generally accepted, would destroy economics as a
separate intellectual discipline, or, at least, would reduce it back to
political economy from which it emerged in the eighteenth century. But
the warnings of this book should be considered by citizens who must pay
the price in freedom, comfort, safety, and blood, if the description of
our economy and of the “American Way of Life” presented here is true in
only a major part. I do not think there is any likelihood of our
citizens doing this, especially as the book is too long, repetitive; and
even verbose, relieved only occasionally by the touches of verbal humor,
clever phrase-making, and smart-aleck allusions of which the author is
so capable.
The volume is not as original as its readers will claim (or as it
may appear to those who have not read Adolph A. Berle, Jr.) although
this is the first time, I believe, that many of these ideas have been
brought together by an economist to give a picture of the American
economic system as a whole. The effect is stunning. I myself have been
teaching almost everything in its separate chapters since the end of
1943, yet the total picture as shown here was almost a revelation.
As I read this book, I kept thinking, If only Galbraith could write
like Robert Heilbroner. Or "If only Heilbroner (whose THE LIMITS OF
AMERICAN CAPITALISM, published last year, tried to look at the same
subject as this volume) could look, as Galbraith can, through the
thickets of rationalization, verbiage, accepted myth, and stereotypes,
which pass for truth in American academic life today. Lacking this, I
can only hope that citizens may form small groups to read and discuss,
in sequence, Heilbroner’s brief 134 page book, than plow through this
volume chapter by chapter, discussing and re-wording it as they go
along, and end up by reading Eisenhower’s last presidential speech
warning us to beware of the "military-industrial complex."
These citizens would see an American economy of almost 12 million
enterprises dominated by only a few hundred super-corporations.
According to Heilbroner, the latter "tiny group of immense corporations
constitutes a bastion of formidable economic strength within the
sprawling expanse of the American economy -- indeed, that it forms a
virtual economic system within an economic system.” Galbraith contends
that the motivations, methods, and "economic laws" which operate in
these two systems are totally different, that economists are teaching
myths and fantasies because they continue to teach the rules worked out
to explain the behavior of the more than 11 million unimportant
enterprises when, in fact, the economy and the future are being
dominated by the small number of super-corporations, and that the
failure of economists to look at the facts and their insistence on
teaching what is little more than a justification of the economy as it
was a few decades ago make it very difficult for anyone to see what the
economy is like today and thus allow the managers of the
super-corporations to carry on almost unnoticed, a wholesale
transformation of American life. I might add that the ignorance by most
historians of economics put the historians in the same boat, in blinding
students and the American people as to what is going on.
What is going on, according to Galbraith, is a total transformation
of economic rules, motivations, behavior, and goals in the mega-economy
of the super-corporations (which he calls, rather limply, the
"industrial economy") in contrast to the economy of the older system of
the vast multitude of enterprises (which he calls, with more accuracy,
the "entrepreneurial economy").
The “entrepreneurial economy” is based on decision-making through a
management controlled by the owners; it seeks to maximize profits for
these owners; its area of autonomy and free decision is narrow, hemmed
in by government, labor, competitors, and the free choice of consumers;
and its most significant decisions, such as levels of prices and
production for its products, are almost completely out of its control in
the "competitive market." Living thus, dangerously, almost like a
beleaguered fortress in the jungle of economic competition, such
enterprises die like flies, with only a very small minority surviving to
celebrate a tenth or twenty-fifth birthday. These older forms of
enterprise sought to maximize the income of owners, that is dividends,
by maximizing profits, and saw rising wages or taxes, or interest rates,
or shifting public tastes as direct and almost uncontrollable threats to
the enterprise's primary aim, since these evils could neither be
controlled nor shifted to any weaker elements in the system but had to
be paid out of the owner's share of the enterprise's income.
The super-corporation in the mega-economy is entirely different. It
is controlled by its management (what Galbraith calls “the
technostructure”), who seek, not production nor profits nor higher
dividends, and certainly not "maximization of profits" but seek POWER.
To be sure, profits are sought, but only as an intermediate goal on the
way to the organization's real goal, power. Such profits are used as
means of building up the autonomy of that power by freeing the
enterprise from interference by the owners or of the capital-markets,
while dividends are declared only to the amount needed to keep the
stockholders quiet, while the profits which are not distributed are
available to be used by the technostructure to free themselves from the
need to seek outside capital, and thus free themselves from finance and
banking, which, fifty years ago, was able to dominate most large
corporations. At the same time, the decline of competition in the
mega-economy makes it possible for the technostructure to fix prices, to
plan production and expansion, and to pay higher taxes, wages, or even
dividends, simply by shifting the burden of these to outsiders by
raising prices. This ends the struggles found in the older competitive
economy and allows labor, owners, government, and fellow producers to
stop fighting each other and to work out mutually beneficial divisions
of wealth and power, in an economy which emphasizes hard-ware over
people and at the expanse of the conditions of life of the people as a
whole.
In this new system (whose characteristics were described in Swiss
and German publications more than twenty-five years ago), the two most
significant elements which remain outside the control of the
technostructure are: (1) aggregate demand, that is the total purchasing
power available in the community to buy the products of the
super-corporation; and (2) shifting consumers' tastes or needs, which
could leave the corporation's products unbought.
To protect itself against the former problem, the technostructure
has worked out a modus vivendi with government, in which the government,
in cooperation with the mega-economy, sees that aggregate demand is
sufficient to absorb what the super-corporations produce, To some extent
this is achieved by fiscal policy, but increasingly it is being achieved
by the government itself buying what the mega-economy produces. This
short-circuits any unpredictable consumer freedom by allowing the
individual citizens to pay for what the mega-economy produces through
the government in the form of taxes rather than by the super-corporation
having to cater to the market or to take the risks of having to
condition or anticipate the buying reactions of millions of individuals.
Since it would be no solution for the government to buy consumers’
goods (such as passenger cars or TV sets), which would endanger the
domestic market for such goods (unless they could be dumped abroad,
which would injure the export market for such goods), there has been a
steady tendency for the mega-economy to increase its production of those
goods, such as armaments or aerospace equipment, for which only the
government is purchaser and which do not return to the domestic market
to use up domestic consumers purchasing power (although these items
often do reappear in the international market for second-hand armaments
to stir up political instability and provide weapons for potential
guerrillas all over the world, a development which may seem regrettable
at first glance to citizens but, in the long run, helps many
corporations by stimulating the American government’s demand for new
"hard-ware" to help repress the resulting political instabilities).
The mega-economy’s response to the problem of shifting consumers'
tastes and freedom of consumers’ choice, or the more dangerous threat of
the satiation of consumers’ demand, has, according to Galbraith, been
met by mental conditioning of consumers to the point where a
well-financed advertising campaign can create needs, even urgent needs,
which were never conceived of before in human history, such as changing
the color, length, and straightness of women’s hair to match her
garments and varied daily activities. For this end we are systematically
brainwashed, and our whole way of life is being reshaped, distorted, and
corrupted to provide markets for the mega-economy.
According to Galbraith, the technostructure which makes the
decisions in the super-corporations does so, not by individual authority
but through a group consensus achieved in committees at a relatively low
level in the corporate hierarchy, and the officers of the company
function as presiding agents, to ratify or promulgate committee
decisions. This need he says, is based on the wide range of specialized
knowledge which has to be consulted in such decision-making. A similar
process is used in government and in other economies based on advanced
technology, as in the Soviet Union. This, according to the author, makes
it possible not only for government and technostructure to make joint
decisions, but also make it possible for the United States and the
Soviet Union to agree.
Galbraith's title, THE NEW INDUSTRIAL STATE, rests on his belief that
the older sharp distinction between private and public (or industry and
the state) no longer is true of the mega-economy, in which, by a process
of osmosis and mutual penetration, government and the super-corporations
have arrived at a symbiotic system of tacit mutual reciprocal adjustment
and understanding through constant conferences and interchange of
personnel to reach mutually satisfactory decisions which are neither
public nor private, but which determine the future for all persons
(except the few who choose to "drop out" of the American way of life).
According to Galbraith, the goal of the super-corporations is
power, to be achieved by growth, that is by the corporation's neurotic
drive to expand without limit in order to bring under its influence all
the elements of its economic and social environment so that these can
becontrolled in an autonomous system by the technostructure. To explain
this urge, which drives the members of the technostructure to longer and
longer hours of work, and to deeper and deeper involvement in the
"rat-race" which leads to the top, to ulcers, heart-failure, and to
shattered family life, Galbraith examines, somewhat inadequately, the
motivations of businessmen and firmly rejects the usual economic theory
which holds that they are working to increase their monetary incomes.
Instead, he finds their chief motivations in what he calls
"identification" and "adaptation." He does not go sufficiently behind
these words to link them with the corporation's drive for power and
incessant growth as he should have, but the implication seems to be that
men who have failed to achieve personal identity and are psychically
insecure in their personality patterns seek such security by
identification with an organization in which they can share in a drive
for power which helps to assuage their own inadequacies. These are of
course, the same paranoid motivations which were the basis for joining
or condoning the Nazi Party organizations, although Galbraith, who makes
much of the converging social patterns of the Soviet Union and the
United States, makes no comparisons with Nazi Germany. This may be part
of his growing verbal caution in the latter part of this volume, in
which discretion frequently stops him from drawing the obvious
conclusions of his own statements. To me his description of the American
economy as he sees it has a very disturbing similarity to the impression
received in 1912 on reading Part Two of Franz Neumann’s BEHEMOTH: THE
STRUCTURE AND PRACTICE OF NATIONAL SOCIALISM. An economy driving
neurotically for limitless expansion in a search for power and seeking
to obtain total control of the factors which can influence its own
activities (and which is blurring the distinction between the
mega-economy and the government by constant interchange of personal,
techniques, and joint or parallel decision-making) can hardly fail to
lead to disaster, and the parallel should not be overlooked because the
relative balance between mental-conditioning and compulsion is quite
different in the two systems. Galbraith, however, stops well short of
examining these possibilities.
On the contrary, the careful reader of this book will notice a
rather drastic change of tone and expression about three-quarters of the
way through the volume: the tone becomes more critical, even alarmist,
but the wording becomes more circumspect and evasive. He puts the
mega-economy in its social context and shows how, like a cancerous
growth (my words, not his), its search for power makes it necessary for
it to take over all aspects of life: education, government, social
living, our very thoughts and emotional reactions, in a gigantic
brain-washing operation which will bring all life under the domination
of the mega economy. Strangely enough, he has little to say about one
chief aspect of this, the influence of the mega-economy on the mass
media, especially the press. But he is very concerned about its impact
on the educational system, where he sees the mega-economy steadily
modifying the process of education and educational administration so
that these also adopt the mega-economic goals of endless physical
expansion, financed by the system in return for educational efforts to
shape and condition the young into the narrowly trained, uncritical,
materialistic persons which the mega-economy needs for its personnel and
its customers. He is equally alarmed at its effect on government and our
foreign policy, taking over the one and directing the other toward
increasing militarization of policy and all life.
As in his earlier AFFLUENT SOCIETY, he shows that what the
mega-economy wants done (like super-highways or moon-shots) is done, but
what the mega-economy is not interested in (like legal, judicial, or tax
reform, care of emotionally disturbed children, noise or pollution
abatement, primary education or safety in the city streets) is not done.
Galbraith implies that the influence of the mega-economy in these
matters may well be unconscious, as simply unanticipated consequences of
the technostructure’s drive for its narrow and specific goals.
The critical tone of the latter part of this book is in sharp contrast
with the earlier and major part of the volume, where he gives the
impression that the development of the mega-economy is not only
inevitable but also good. He attributes it to advancing technology and
shows little real feeling that such technology and the resulting
mega-economy with its technostructure are either undesirable or
dangerous. Basing these on growing technology, he assumes that this is
inevitable and desirable, and even justifies the technostructure’s
striving for power on the ground that power in the economy has always
rested on whichever factor in the productive process was most difficult
to obtain, a condition which allowed those who controlled that supply to
use that control as a road to power. Thus he lists the customary
economic factors of production (such as land, labor, capital, know-how)
and decides that power in the economy has always gone, in any period,
"to the factor which is hardest to obtain or hardest to replace." Thus
power rested with land two centuries ago, shifted to capital, when the
need for that factor became acute, a century ago, but now rests with
know-how, since that is the factor in shortest supply today. Thus, the
author justifies the dominant role of management, not only within the
super-corporation but outside it as the technostructure steadily extends
the area and scope of its power seeking to control all our actions,
patterns of living, values, and thoughts, so that the corporation may
continue to grow.
In the same way, Galbraith justifies, in his early pages, the
growth of the managerial bureaucracy as an anonymous group, for whose
decisions no individual can be held responsible and which must be
accepted as inevitable natural phenomena, on the ground that the
management must function in committee in order to pool the diverse
knowledge and varied talents of the many kinds of expertise necessary
for modern technological complexities. I think this is rationalization
and suspect that Galbraith does too. Committees do not function with the
honest give-and-take of diverse real talents and knowledge which he
pictures, except on the engineering level, and one of the basic things
about the mega-economy is that the engineers are being shoved lower and
lower down the totem-pole by the "stylists", salesmen, gadgeteers,
phrasemakers, and advertisers. This was shown long ago by Veblen in his
THE ENGINEERS AND THE PRICE SYSTEM and is clearly shown to be true today
in the dominant sector of the mega-economy) in the least discussed
chapter of Ralph Nader's book on automobile safety. Galbraith’s defense
of the technostructure (chapters 5 and 6) as a mechanism for reaching a
consensus of diverse talents and knowledge is another American
industrial myth. All diversity is eliminated from the technostructure
low down in the hierarchy to form a homogeneous general outlook with
almost identical basic assumptions and anyone who does not share those
assumptions will not voice his divergence at policy-making committee
meetings. The diversity which may be present is narrowly technical but
not technological and is not concerned with what should be done but with
how it should be done, so that the whole discussion is concerned with
means, never with goals, just as in academic meetings.
The technostructure is not only fanatically devoted to growth but
has set up criteria for measuring growth which fit what they want to do.
They are concerned with quantity not quality, and then try to persuade
us that the massive increase of quantity is really quality, whether it
is or not. They have, assisted by economists, devised terms like
"standards of living" or "affluence" in which almost everything which
makes life worth living, such as leisure, love, peace, decency, nature,
and all amenities, are excluded, and can than produce figures to show us
how much better off we are when they have destroyed these things. Their
obsession with mass material transformation buries us in traffic,
pollution, erosion, and noise, but they succeed in convincing most
people, and can get economists, statisticians, and government officials
to produce figures to “prove” it. In his last seven chapters, Galbraith
looks at the future of this "Industrial State" and makes suggestions to
reform it. Here his alarm is apparent, but the discussion is both feeble
and unrealistic. These last chapters could have been an alarm ball
clanging in the night. Instead, they are a muffled drum, so muffled that
neither the message nor the direction of the sound is clear. We can be
saved, he believes, by "the intellectual and scientific estate", who
must provide the necessary "political lead". The first task of these
intellectuals will be to break the mega-economy’s grasp on education,
especially higher education. He warns that no reliance can be placed by
these reforming intellectuals on economists, for the “economic
stereotypes -- the productive models that lend themselves to
assembly-line instruction -- insist on the approved sequence.... they
will continue to do so.” Quite so, but what Galbraith ignores is that
economists are no better and no worse than any other intellectuals,
scientists, and academicians; they are all mostly narrowly educated
men-of-good-will trying to make a living, products of the educational
system and society whose condition, according to Galbraith, is so bad it
must be reformed. Galbraith should guard himself against the normal
human error of believing that the people one knows best are worst than
those one knows less well.
Even Galbraith, with all his broadness and background, is not able
to offer a suggested reform nor even to see what is coming. His reform
is old (and I had hoped discredited), that of more socialism (not his
word) by trying to balance the magaeconomy through increasing the sphere
of action of the state. This is based on his belief that the state is
independent of the mega-economy and can stand up against it, two points
that his book shows to be untrue— In fact, his vision of the future,
which sees the state and the mega-economy merging into symbiosis in
which the distinction of public and private is no longer significant,
sees this as a process by which the state is taking over the
mega-economy. This is naive, for it is clearly a process by which the
technostructure is taking over the state by conditioning its major
goals, motives, techniques, and personnel.
Galbraith’s weakness in thinking on remedies and the future rests
on two simple facts: he is too weak in history and in the social and
psychological roots of our present crisis. He may distrust the
economists, but he remains one of them. From the beginnings of economic
thinking, six generations ago, economists ignored what every
entrepreneur knew: that the "factors of production" included not only
the "economic factors of land, labor, capital, management, and the rest
but required two preliminary needs: an acquisitive outlook in the people
and domestic tranquillity in the land. As soon as economics ceased to be
"political economy", the economists forgot these two, simply because the
industrial system then had them, but, from before 1750 to after 1850,
whatever economic thinkers believed, all businessmen and politicians saw
the need for these two. Capitalism and industrialism could not function
without the first: that subjective outlook and value-system which
included self-discipline, punctuality, future-preference, and infinitely
expandible material demand -- what historians all "the acquisitive
outlook." Lack of this outlook has been the chief obstacle in the
introduction of modern industrial society into Asia, Africa, and Latin
America, despite our efforts, costing billions of dollars, to give these
areas the "economic factors" of production. We have been equally
unsuccessful in introducing this outlook to at least one-sixth of our
own people, as can be seen in any American urban slum. The British
however gave it to their own people, largely in 1820-1850, through what
they call "Non-Conformist religion."
The other neglected, but essential, non-economic factor of
production is what we call "law and order", but our wiser ancestors
called "domestic tranquillity"; it covers personal physical security and
safety, respect for property, and non-violent settlement of personal
disputes. The chief task of Britain, in the eyes of businessmen in
1790-1850, was to obtain these two things. The economists ignore this
fact. Today both are vanishing rapidly. One the one hand, the
middle-class adolescents are contracting out of the acquisitive outlook,
while the slum adolescents, who never had it, are turning our cities
into jungles. Both groups show their resentments against Galbraith’s
"Industrial State" by vandalism, increasing crimes against persons, and
vandalism on property. Many others are simply refusing to join the
system, with neither violence nor animosity, turning away from it to try
to make their own non-affluent, non-competitive life outside the
"American way of life”. In the last few years, middle-class young people
have shown their rejection of it by decreased enrollments in
engineering, exact sciences, and business studies, and, above all by a
35% drop in applications for jobs in industry, at a time when total
enrollments and applications to the Peace Corps are rising.
The future of the Industrial State will not be settled by any
superficial reforms by intellectuals in education or society as a whole,
and not I hope, by more socialism, but by many persons dropping out, in
every way possible, probably by guerrilla warfare in American cities,
and by the increasing numbers who come to believe that all vital reforms
occur in peoples; minds and hearts. That was how it happened, to an The
critical tone of the latter part of oppressive system similar to ours,
in the Roman Empire about 1700 years ago.
Carroll Quigley
////////////////////////////////////
A Review of Galbraith’s New Industrial State
and of Carroll Quigley's Analysis
by Josef Solterer, Ph.D.
Past Chairman, GU Economics Department
Carroll Quigley, in the most circumspect review of the New
Industrial State I have seen, The Sunday Star, June 25, 1967, shows in
his opening sentence the significance of this book for the work of our
committee. He writes: "This is am immensely important book. It should be
read, analyzed, and unemotionally discussed, not by economists, but by
citizens. The economists, as most academicians, are hampered by their
specialist training from seeing their subject in the full social
context, and will be particularly offended by this volume, whose
lessons, if generally accepted, would destroy economics as a separate
intellectual discipline, or, at least, would reduce it back to political
economy from which it emerged in the eighteenth century."
Formally expressed, the book deals with the problem of the
dialectical interrelations of man's work and himself (about 3/4 of the
book) and the consequences of these in the ordering of society, in which
task the leading role is assigned to an academic elite.
The mere posing of this problem, quite foreign to traditional U.S.
thinking, and broadcasting it as a best seller, justifies. in my
opinion, Quigley's opening sentence.
Without acknowledging it, the author actually elaborates the
dependence effect of his earlier work, i.e., the abandoning of the
concept of consumers' sovereignty, substituting for it the technical
requirements of production as the last reason for producing and
influencing the public and the government by advertising and by other
means to want to consume just this output.
This book is written by a passionate reformer, rather than by a
sober scholar. Thus no connections are sought with the work of Engel,
Schumpeter, Veblen, Berle & Means, of recent Marxist philosophers on
alienation, of mathematicians as Schouten & Becker, Pfaff's problem and
differential analyzer as dialectical models and of still other writers
among whom Teilhard de Chardin certainly occupies a foremost place among
modern students of development.
This emphasis and its shortcoming, I felt particularly in the last
part of the book, dealing with the proposals of ordering future social
life. It is self-contradictory, assertive, and angry.
In this respect, it seems to me that it might be useful, at a later
stage of our work, to study Professor Rudolf Aller's reflections, who in
his last years took up the problem of the dialectics of work. Here are
three articles by him on this subject: a) The Product: Remarks on the
Metaphysics of Human Creativity, 1958; b) The Subjective and Objective,
1959; c) Reflections on Cooperation and Communication, 1960
The neglect of associating his work with that of other students of
dialectical systems, as well as his reformist ardor, might be an
explanation why Galbraith, the Scotch dissenter, despaired in finding
wisdom among all people and limit future esthetic and moral insight to
an academic elite, without indicating, however, how or why only these
people would arrive at such precious knowledge.
Galbraith, as did Veblen and Berle & Means, his unacknowledged
American ancestors, rejected as unreal, the basic assumptions of
classical economic theory, and most current economic teaching, and also
of the ancient common law tradition that the economy consists of a large
number of small firms without market power who can only adjust their
actions to the sovereign will of consumers. His evidence that only a
small group of large corporations dominates American economic life is
exaggerated to the degree of falsification; nevertheless, this assertion
serves well as an illustration of a more general way of considering a
social economy. It involves not only an adjustment of given scarce means
to independent wants and technologies, or poses not only an optimization
problem of allocation of resources so defined, but rather becomes an
integration problem of a continuously innovating technostructure seeking
the power of remaining and growing.
Galbraith indicates, again in vastly exaggerated terms, how this
happened in the U.S. The giant corporations freed themselves from the
control of outside finance. They acquired the capacity to influence
aggregate demand to absorb the output which the technostructure demanded
by the management of wants, and they transformed their decision makers
and employees from independents, seeking their largest personal profit
to teamworkers who adjust their goals to the common end of the
super-corporations of growing ever larger.
This mega-economy, according to Galbraith, depends also on the
cooperation of the government, who purchases that part of the
ever-increasing output which cannot be absorbed by the consuming public
and which takes the form of military hardware to deal with the political
instabilities all over the world.
This symbiosis of the technostructure and political government is
the New Industrial State in this country and, according to in Galbraith,
is indistinguishable from that of the Soviet Union or any other modern
industrial state.
Throughout the major part of the book, there is the suggestion that
the expansionist drive, the emergence of giant industrial organizations,
their fusion with the government and the adaptation of personal wills to
the requirements of the technostructure is an inevitable consequence of
an advancing technology.
Later, however, this is called an evil, cancerous growth, which
brings all life in a gigantic brain-washing operation under the
domination of the techno-structure.
The salvation is to come from the "intellectual and scientific
estate" whose task is to break the strangle hold of the industrial state
on higher education, via separation of government from the mega-economy;
indeed a strange remedy to suggest after having spent the larger part of
the book in the demonstration that the mega-economy has taken over the
government and this not by arbitrary acts of will but by the necessities
of expansion.
Galbraith appears to me, bewildered in his outlook on the future.
Quigley concurs in this judgment, and adds that Galbraith, still a
narrow economist despite his attempted escape to a broader vision of
social life, forgets to consider two preliminary needs for orderly
economic development without the danger of losing personal independence:
An acquisitive outlook by all and domestic tranquility.
For our purpose, however, of extracting guidelines, for assessing
the future role of Georgetown, I would judge Galbraith's work
differently. As mentioned earlier, I see its merit, despite all
exaggerations and inconsistencies, in his suggesting as the major
educational problem of our times and the future, the problem of
integrability of dialectical processes in all fields; the establishment
of their ends or the invariances in development, which could serve as
goals in the restructuring academic action.
It so happens that Father Hesburgh, speaking on the future of Notre
Dame apparently had similar thoughts. In his address at the conclusion
of a recent symposium for U.S. educators, he saw greatness rather than
excellence for a catholic university in dedicating itself to the further
exploration of the two paths of human development, as have been
indicated by Teilhard de Chardin, one involving the humanization of all
creation by man, and the other, the supernatural transformation embodied
in the Christian Message. All universities, he said, are committed to
the former end. Catholic universities must also be concerned with the
Teilhardian supernatural development. Father Hesburgh mentioned that
this comeback to greatness has already begun in many places, Notre Dame
being one of them.
January, 1968
Scan of
original
Correspondence – Dr. Carroll Quigley & Dr. Josef Solterer - 1977
|
Please email the editors (editors@carrollquigley.net)
with corrections, questions, or if you have other works by Professor Quigley you
would like to see posted.
©2008-2018 All rights reserved. CarrollQuigley.net |
|
|